sábado, 30 de junho de 2012

How Much is Enough? Money and the Good Life

http://www.otherpress.com/books/book?ean=9781590515075

A provocative and timely call for a moral approach to economics, drawing on philosophers, political theorists, writers, and economists from Aristotle to Marx to Keynes.

What constitutes the good life? What is the true value of money? Why do we work such long hours merely to acquire greater wealth? These are some of the questions that many asked themselves when the financial system crashed in 2008. This book tackles such questions head-on.
The authors begin with the great economist John Maynard Keynes. In 1930 Keynes predicted that, within a century, per capita income would steadily rise, people’s basic needs would be met, and no one would have to work more than fifteen hours a week. Clearly, he was wrong: though income has increased as he envisioned, our wants have seemingly gone unsatisfied, and we continue to work long hours.
The Skidelskys explain why Keynes was mistaken. Then, arguing from the premise that economics is a moral science, they trace the concept of the good life from Aristotle to the present and show how our lives over the last half century have strayed from that ideal. Finally, they issue a call to think anew about what really matters in our lives and how to attain it.
How Much Is Enough? is that rarity, a work of deep intelligence and ethical commitment accessible to all readers. It will be lauded, debated, cited, and criticized. It will not be ignored.

Geoffrey Ingham : The Nature of Money

http://www.polity.co.uk/book.asp?ref=9780745609966
Geoffrey Ingham is Reader in Sociology and Political Economy; and Fellow of Christ’s College.

In this important new book, Geoffrey Ingham draws on neglected traditions in the social sciences to develop a theory of the `social relation' of money.
  • Genuinely multidisciplinary approach, based on a thorough knowledge of theories of money in the social sciences 
  • An original development of the neglected heterodox theories of money
  • New histories of the origins and development of forms of money and their social relations of production in different monetary systems 
  • A radical interpretation of capitalism as a particular type of monetary system and the first sociological outline of the institutional structure of the social production of capitalist money 
  • A radical critique of recent writing on global e-money, the so-called `end of money', and new monetary spaces such as the euro.

Christian Tutin : Une histoire des théories monétaires par les textes

http://www.laprocure.com/histoire-theories-monetaires-textes/9782081228788.html
Quel rôle la monnaie joue-t-elle dans l'apparition des crises économiques ? Quelle est son influence sur le volume du commerce et le niveau de l'emploi ? La croissance entraîne-t-elle nécessairement l'inflation ? Peut-on contrôler la masse monétaire ? Depuis le XVIIe siècle, philosophes, économistes et théoriciens de la monnaie n'ont cessé de reprendre ces interrogations, de John Locke à Friedrich Hayek, en passant par John Law, Adam Smith, Karl Marx, Knut Wicksell, John Maynard Keynes ou Milton Friedman.

Ce livre propose une anthologie des principaux textes qui ont marqué l'histoire des théories monétaires, dont certains encore inédits en français. Des mercantilistes aux néolibéraux contemporains, c'est en particulier le thème de la « neutralité » de la monnaie, toujours démentie par la réalité des crises, qui sert ici de fil rouge. Une question controversée, qui reste au coeur des débats actuels et des décisions de politique économique de notre temps.

sexta-feira, 29 de junho de 2012

“Those who can make you believe absurdities can make you commit atrocities.”
- Voltaire

Lorna Salzman - Politics as if Evolution Mattered : Darwin, Ecology and Social Justice



http://www.lornasalzman.com/collectedwritings.html

In this scientifically authoritative essay collection, Salzman, a seasoned and provocative environmentalist, demonstrates how evolutionary theory penetrates nearly all aspects of human society. She faults social justice movements for their short-sighted focus on human needs to the exclusion of nonhuman nature and stresses the potential of evolutionary thought for replacing religious and secular ideologies with an ecological paradigm for broad social change. Salzman's special concern is the resurgence of irrationality, anti-intellectualism and anti-science attitudes.. She explodes the myth of genetic determinism promoted in popular media, discrediting the belief that natural selection involves violence. In place of the arbitrary "economism" of socialists and the free marketeers' faith in untrammeled economic growth, she envisions a human society modeled on interdependent self-regulating natural systems.

A graduate of Cornell University, Lorna Salzman has been an environmental activist, writer, lecturer and organizer for forty years. In the early 1970s, under the auspices of Citizens for Local Democracy, co-founded by the late Walter Karp, she edited a Brooklyn Heights NY community paper, The Township, dedicated to neighborhood government and political decentralization.

Later she was hired by the late David Brower, founder and president of Friends of the Earth (FOE), as the regional representative of FOE and held that position for nearly ten years, concentrating on anti-nuclear work and on coastal zone and wetlands protection on eastern Long Island.

Read more about Lorna Salzman : http://www.lornasalzman.com/bio.html

quinta-feira, 28 de junho de 2012

Mary Mellor - The Future of Money : From Financial Crisis to Public Resource




As the recent financial crisis has revealed, the state is central to the stability of the money system, while the chaotic privately-owned banks reap the benefits without shouldering the risks. This book argues that money is a public resource that has been hijacked by capitalism.

Mary Mellor explores the history of money and modern banking, showing how finance capital has captured bank-created money to enhance speculative ‘leveraged’ profits as well as destroying collective approaches to economic life. Meanwhile, most individuals, and the public economy, have been mired in debt. To correct this obvious injustice, Mellor proposes a public and democratic future for money. Ways are put forward for structuring the money and banking system to provision societies on an equitable, ecologically sustainable ‘sufficiency’ basis.

This fascinating study of money should be read by all economics students looking for an original analysis of the economy during the current crisis.

Mary Mellor is Emeritus Professor at Northumbria University in Newcastle, where she was founding Chair of the University’s Sustainable Cities Research Institute. She has published extensively on alternative economics integrating socialist, feminist and green perspectives. Her books include The Politics of Money: Towards Sustainability And Economic Democracy (Pluto, 2002).

Source : http://www.plutobooks.com/display.asp?K=9780745329949

Jack M. Balkin - Constitutional Redemption : Political Faith in an Unjust World

http://www.hup.harvard.edu/catalog.php?isbn=9780674058743

Political constitutions, hammered out by imperfect human beings in periods of intense political controversy, are always compromises with injustice. What makes the U.S. Constitution legitimate, argues this daring book, is Americans’ enduring faith that the Constitution’s promises can someday be redeemed, and the constitutional system be made “a more perfect union.”

A leading constitutional theorist, Balkin argues eloquently that the American constitutional project is based in faith, hope, and a narrative of shared redemption. Our belief that the Constitution will deliver us from evil shows in the stories we tell one another about where our country came from and where it is headed, and in the way we use these historical touchstones to justify our fervent (and opposed) political creeds. Because Americans have believed in a story of constitutional redemption, we have assumed the right to decide for ourselves what the Constitution means, and have worked to persuade others to set it on the right path. As a result, constitutional principles have often shifted dramatically over time. They are, in fact, often political compromises in disguise.

What will such a Constitution become? We cannot know. But our belief in the legitimacy of the Constitution requires a leap of faith—a gamble on the ultimate vindication of a political project that has already survived many follies and near-catastrophes, and whose destiny is still over the horizon.

Jack M. Balkin is Knight Professor of Constitutional Law and the First Amendment at Yale Law School. Professor Balkin received his Ph.D in philosophy from Cambridge University, and his A.B. and J.D. degrees from Harvard University. He served as a clerk for Judge Carolyn D. King of the United States Court of Appeals for the Fifth Circuit and practiced as an attorney at Cravath, Swaine, and Moore in New York City before entering the legal academy.

Cultural Software : A Theory of Ideology - A New Theory of Memetics and Ideology

http://www.yale.edu/lawweb/jbalkin/cs.htm

Cultural Software explains ideology as a result of the cultural evolution of bits of cultural knowhow, or memes. It is the first book to apply theories of cultural evolution to the problem of ideology and justice.

Download an online version of Cultural Software under a Creative Commons Noncommercial Sharealike license.

Cultural Software offers a new theory about how ideologies and beliefs grow, spread, and develop-- a theory of cultural evolution, which explains both shared understandings and disagreement and diversity within cultures.

Cultural evolution occurs through transmission and spread of cultural information and know-how-- or "cultural software "-- in human minds. Individuals embody cultural software: they are literally information made flesh. They spread it to others through communication and social learning. Human minds and institutions provide the ecology in which cultural software grows, thrives, and develops. Human cultural software is created out of the diverse elements of cultural transmission, also known as "memes."

Ideology is not a special or deviant pathology of thinking but arises from the ordinary mechanisms of human thought. Because cultural understanding is the product of evolution, it is always a patchwork quilt of older imperfect tools of understanding continually readapted to solve new problems. As a result human understanding is always partly adequate and partly inadequate to understanding and to the pursuit of justice. Cultural Software offers examples drawn from many different disciplines showing how ideological effects arise and how they contribute to injustice.

The book also tackles the problem of mutual understanding between different world views. It shows how both ideological analysis of others and ideological self-criticism are possible and argues that cultural understanding presupposes transcendent ideals. These arguments should be especially relevant to current debates over multiculturalism, and to philosophers and political theorists who worry that different cultures have incommensurable normative conceptions.

Cultural Software
draws upon many different areas of study, including anthropology, evolutionary theory, linguistics, sociology, political theory, philosophy, social psychology and law. The book's explanation of how shared understandings arise, how cultures grow and spread, and how people of different cultures can understand and critique each other's views should be relevant to work in many different areas of the human sciences.
"Il serait inique que des barbouilleurs animés par un esprit civique de dépollution des images soient poursuivis et condamnés, alors que tant d'ignominies dues à la recherche du profit maximum sont tolérées."
- Edgar Morin.

quarta-feira, 27 de junho de 2012

Agnès Rousseaux : La nourriture du futur que nous concocte l’industrie agroalimentaire

http://www.bastamag.net/article2498.html
Hamburgers in vitro, fromages de synthèse, glu de porc, vache ou poisson transgénique… Le tout agrémenté d’une bonne pincée de chimie. L’industrie agroalimentaire multiplie les expérimentations, et commence à inonder le marché de ces nouveaux produits, davantage fabriqués en usines ou en labos que dans les champs. Objectif : nourrir la planète au moindre coût. Sans trop s’attarder sur les conséquences sanitaires et écologiques. Et sans pitié pour les cobayes que nous sommes. Basta ! vous présente le menu agro-industriel de demain.
Miam !
Cela ressemble à de la guimauve rose liquide. Cette mixture de viande est obtenue en passant les carcasses de poulet ou de porc dans une centrifugeuse à haute température, ce qui permet de récupérer le moindre morceau de barbaque. Les tendons, graisses, tissus conjonctifs sont transformés en pâte. À l’arrivée dans l’assiette, le « lean finely textured beef » (bœuf maigre à texture fine) est utilisé depuis quinze ans « sans restrictions » aux États-Unis.
[Lire la suite]

Jean Gadrey : La nature, nouvelle frontière du capitalisme financier

http://alternatives-economiques.fr/blogs/gadrey
On dit souvent que « le monde n’est pas une marchandise » ou que « la nature n’est pas à vendre ». On critique la « marchandisation » au nom des biens communs. On a souvent raison, mais c’est plus compliqué que cela : si l’on défend des coopératives locales d’énergies renouvelables ou une filière écologique régionale de production de bois de chauffage ou de bois construction en veillant à la biodiversité dans la gestion des forêts, on crée aussi des marchés et cela n’a rien de critiquable, au contraire.

Si l’économie verte dont on nous parle c’était cela, on ne pourrait que la défendre. C’est ainsi que le PNUE nous la présente en des termes aimables : une économie qui « entraîne une amélioration du bien-être humain et de l’équité sociale tout en réduisant de manière significative les risques environnementaux et la pénurie de ressources ».

Quel est pourtant le problème posé aujourd’hui et révélé notamment par les mobilisations autour de Rio+20 ?

Il est dans les stratégies actuelles des multinationales (et de la finance actionnariale et spéculative qui les contrôle), appuyées par les États les plus expansionnistes, et exerçant leur influence jusqu’au sein des Nations Unies.

Le capitalisme financier est en crise profonde. Dans son aveuglement, il distingue des planches de salut vertes et il sait que des contraintes écologiques fortes se profilent avec lesquelles il va devoir composer.

Comment transformer – si possible - ces contraintes en opportunités ? Pour le capitalisme financier, il existe plusieurs stratégies, liées à une idée de valorisation lucrative de la nature et de ses biens communs, qu’il faut dé-communaliser pour les mettre à son service.

C’est sa version de l’économie verte, celle qu’il a infiltrée non sans succès au sein des Nations unies. C’est aussi celle de la commission européenne. Voici ce que dit Janez Potocnik, commissaire à l’environnement de l’Union Européenne : « Nous devons passer d’une situation où l’environnement était protégé du business au fait d’utiliser le business pour protéger l’environnement ».

Comment faire entrer cette conviction néolibérale dans les faits ? En suivant trois stratégies, ensemble ou séparément. Je mets délibérément de côté les stratégies de « greenwashing », importantes mais auxquelles ne sont pas associés des investissements aussi lourds que dans les stratégies qui suivent.

1. L’APPROPRIATION ELARGIE DES RESSOURCES

La première stratégie est celle de l’appropriation élargie des ressources naturelles existantes ou à découvrir : ressources du sol, des terres, du sous-sol, des océans, en eau potable, des pôles, des forêts, etc. Il s’agit de monter d’un cran dans l’exploitation rentable de ces ressources jugées indispensables à la prolongation de la croissance, de l’avidité consumériste, du « mode de vie occidental ».

C’est une sorte de nouvelle conquête de l’Ouest, mais ici l’Ouest est en général au Sud…

Sont en priorité visées l’appropriation et l’exploitation de la biomasse (toutes les matières organiques végétales ou animales) et de tous ses usages pour produire de l’énergie. Cela se traduit entre autres par la montée en puissance des agrocarburants et autres « pétroles verts ».

Mais dans cette stratégie on trouve aussi les sables bitumineux, les gaz et huiles de schiste, les forages en eau profonde, les méga-barrages, les achats de terres des pays pauvres, la conquête des pôles, la privatisation de la distribution de l’eau, la privatisation des semences et des gènes, etc.

2. ARTIFICIALISER-INDUSTRIALISER LA NATURE ET LE VIVANT

Un grand nombre de multinationales investissent depuis longtemps dans les OGM et cherchent à les imposer dans le monde, mais l’artificialisation du vivant va bien au-delà. On trouve dans le livre « Labo planète », dont j’ai déjà parlé, d’importants exemples relatifs aux NBIC (nanotechnologies, biotechnologies, informatique, sciences cognitives) et à leurs « avancées » dans l’artificialisation, y compris celle des êtres humains.

Selon un article récent de Basta, c’est la biologie de synthèse qui attire le plus les investisseurs. « Les entreprises de biologie synthétique fabriquent de l’ADN de synthèse pour créer sur mesure des algues et des microorganismes qui agissent comme des usines biologiques miniatures. Le but consiste à pouvoir convertir presque n’importe quel type de biomasse en presque n’importe quel produit. »

Le think tank canadien ETC Group a publié un excellent rapport « Qui contrôlera l’économie verte ? ». Extrait : « Jouissant d’investissements publics et privés (incluant les plus grandes entreprises énergétiques et chimiques au monde) totalisant plusieurs milliards de dollars au cours des dernières années, la biologie synthétique voit les divers produits de la nature comme des matières premières servant à alimenter leurs bestioles brevetées – c’est-à-dire des organismes conçus de toutes pièces qui seront utilisés pour transformer la cellulose extraite de plantes en carburants, produits chimiques, plastiques, fibres, produits pharmaceutiques ou même en aliments. »

3. FINANCIARISER LES SERVICES DE LA NATURE

La troisième stratégie vise à créer des marchés et des marchés financiers pour des fonctions techniques remplies par la nature ou « services écosystémique ». C’est plus subtil mais pas moins grave.

La nature nous rend bien des « services » (recycler dans certaines limites des émissions de gaz carbonique, filtrer des eaux, polliniser des plantes, recycler des nutriments, produire du carbone végétal, etc.) sans qu’on s’en rende toujours compte… tant que cette « production » n’est pas menacée ou tant qu’elle est gratuite, ce qui est scandaleux pour le capital financier. Il a bien compris que, puisqu’il y avait menace et risque d’épuisement de ces services, il y avait une opportunité de faire payer, pour peu que des droits de propriété soient instaurés et qu’on définisse des unités de services échangeables.

En plus, nous dit-on, ce serait une très bonne chose pour les pays et les peuples du Sud qui ont tant de services à proposer via leurs immenses ressources de forêts, de biodiversité ou de terres arables. Comment faire ? Il faut découper la nature en « ateliers fonctionnels » - à l’opposé de la logique des écosystèmes - chacun produisant un service mesurable et monnayable, avec des droits de propriété et des contrats de fermage ou de métayage pour ceux qui « produisent » ces services, et avec bien entendu des rentes pour les propriétaires ayant acquis les droits. Et il faut créer de toutes pièces d’abord un marché de ces services, puis des marchés dérivés pour qu’on puisse spéculer sur ces cours nouveaux.

Les plus sophistiquées de ces inventions reposent sur des produits financiers liés à des emprunts hypothécaires gagés sur l’environnement. C’est plus ou moins le modèle des subprimes. Ces emprunts hypothécaires sont proposés à des communautés locales du Sud, pauvres en ressources économiques mais riches en ressources naturelles. Ces communautés peuvent par exemple contracter des micro-crédits à condition qu’elles gèrent bien leur environnement naturel (selon des normes techniques imposées de l’extérieur, et si possible avec des OGM ou d’autres innovations brevetées…), avec l’aide de consultants eux aussi bien rémunérés. Ses promoteurs ne disent pas ce qui adviendra si les débiteurs sont dans l’impossibilité de rembourser, comme ce fut le cas dans la crise des subprimes. C’est ce que les auteurs du très instructif « La nature n’a pas de prix » (Geneviève Azam et Maxime Combes), à qui j’ai emprunté ce paragraphe et certaines autres idées, appellent « la financiarisation de la nature ».

Source : http://alternatives-economiques.fr/blogs/gadrey/2012/06/21/la-nature-nouvelle-frontiere-du-capitalisme-financier/

segunda-feira, 25 de junho de 2012

Western corn rootworm and Bt maize : Challenges of pest resistance in the field

Keywords : Diabrotica virgifera virgifera , cross resistance, insect resistance management, integrated pest management, refuge strategy

Authors : Aaron J. Gassmann, Jennifer L. Petzold-Maxwell, Ryan S. Keweshan and Mike W. Dunbar

Crops genetically engineered to produce insecticidal toxins from the bacterium Bacillus thuringiensis (Bt) manage many key insect pests while reducing the use of conventional insecticides. One of the primary pests targeted by Bt maize in the United States is the western corn rootworm Diabrotica virgifera virgifera LeConte. Beginning in 2009, populations of western corn rootworm were identified in Iowa, USA that imposed severe root injury to Cry3Bb1 maize. Subsequent laboratory bioassays revealed that these populations were resistant to Cry3Bb1 maize, with survival on Cry3Bb1 maize that was three times higher than populations not associated with such injury. Here we report the results of research that began in 2010 when western corn rootworm were sampled from 14 fields in Iowa, half of which had root injury to Cry3Bb1 maize of greater than 1 node. Of these samples, sufficient eggs were collected to conduct bioassays on seven populations. Laboratory bioassays revealed that these 2010 populations had survival on Cry3Bb1 maize that was 11 times higher and significantly greater than that of control populations, which were brought into the laboratory prior to the commercialization of Bt maize for control of corn rootworm. Additionally, the developmental delays observed for control populations on Cry3Bb1 maize were greatly diminished for 2010 populations. All 2010 populations evaluated in bioassays came from fields with a history of continuous maize production and between 3 and 7 y of Cry3Bb1 maize cultivation. Resistance to Cry34/35Ab1 maize was not detected and there was no correlation between survival on Cry3Bb1 maize and Cry34/35Ab1 maize, suggesting a lack of cross resistance between these Bt toxins. Effectively dealing with the challenge of field-evolved resistance to Bt maize by western corn rootworm will require better adherence to the principles of integrated pest management.

Source : http://www.landesbioscience.com/journals/gmcrops/article/20744/4

domingo, 17 de junho de 2012

Polly Higgins - Earth Is Our Business : Changing the Rules of the Game

http://earthisourbusiness.com/
Earth is our Business takes forward the argument of Polly Higgins’ first book, Eradicating Ecocide. This book proposes new Earth law, but it is also about something more than law: it advocates a new form of leadership which places the health and well-being of people and planet first. Polly Higgins shows how law can provide the tools and be a bridge to a new way of doing business. She argues, in fact, that Earth is the business of us all, not the exclusive preserve of the executives of the world’s top corporations.

Expanding on the proposal in her first book to make Ecocide an international crime, this book sets out the institutional framework for sustainable development and international environmental governance. It proposes new rules of the game to transform our economies, energy supplies and political landscape in a radical, but practical, way. The implications of Polly Higgins’ proposal are far-reaching and profound.

Like her award-winning first book, Earth is our Business is written for anyone who is engaging in the new and emerging discourse about the future of our planet. Instead of merely examining the problem, Earth is our Business sets out a solution: new rules of the game. They are, says Polly Higgins, a new set of laws based on the sacredness of all life.

Included as appendices are a draft Ecocide Act, a proposal for revising World Bank investment rules, and the indictment used in the mock Ecocide Trial held in the UK Supreme Court in September 2011.

Eradicating Ecocide won The People’s Book Prize for non-fiction in 2011.


Polly Higgins, barrister and international environmental lawyer, proposed to the United Nations in April 2010 that Ecocide be classed as the 5th Crime Against Peace alongside Genocide, Crimes Against Humanity, Crimes of Aggression and War Crimes.

Her first book set out the starting point for a law of Ecocide; her second book, Earth is our Business: Changing the Rules of the Game, expands on the first book, setting out how such a law could work.
Read the first chapter here.

sábado, 16 de junho de 2012

GRAIN : El gran robo de los alimentos

http://www.icariaeditorial.com/libros.php?id=1301

Cómo las corporaciones controlan los alimentos, acaparan la tierra y destruyen el clima

El gran robo de los alimentos es una colección de materiales producidos por GRAIN durante los últimos años. Pone foco en cómo es que en gran medida los agronegocios son responsables de la crisis climática y cómo es que un fenómeno como el acaparamiento de tierras es promovido por la industria financiera para hacer dinero a partir de la miseria de la gente. Explica también por qué la lucha en pos de la soberanía alimentaria cuestiona estas tendencias y actores y las alternativas posibles.

David Korten : Rio+20: A Defining Choice

David Korten
How can we create an economy that serves the health and well-being of both people and the planet? Follow the Earth’s lead.

Next week, 20 years after the 1992 UN Rio Earth Summit, representatives of the world’s governments will gather again in Rio de Janeiro, Brazil to frame a global response to the Earth’s environmental crisis. Debates leading up to Rio+20 are focusing attention on a foundational choice between two divergent paths to the human future.

The Money Path

For money path advocates, money is the defining measure of value. Profit and growth in financial assets are the bottom line measures by which they assess the performance of both the firm and the economy. They value natural wealth by the price it will fetch in the market and look to global financial markets as the preferred mechanism to organize our human relationships with one another and nature.

They propose that the best way to save nature is to price her assets and sell them to wealthy global investors to hold and manage as their private property. Privatization, commodification, monopolization, and financialization, they assure us, will drive up prices and thus create an incentive to provide for their proper care to maximize a perpetual flow of earnings.
The Life Path

For life path advocates, Earth is our living Mother, sacred and beyond price. Her health and vitality are essential to our well-being and are therefore a priority bottom line measure of economic performance. In return for Earth’s gifts, we have a sacred obligation to future generations to protect and restore to full health the wondrous generative systems by which she replenishes her air, water, fertile soils, fish, forests, and grasslands, and maintains the stable climate on which our health and well-being depend.

Because we receive Earth’s abundance as a gift, we must assure it is shared to meet the needs of all. None among us created this abundance and no one of us has a right to claim it for our exclusive personal benefit.

Money, which is basically a system of accounting, is only a tool useful in facilitating human exchanges beneficial to people and nature. To use financial results as the bottom line indicator of economic performance makes no sense and leads to disastrous results.
Illusions of the Money World

Ignoring the reality that money in itself is nothing but a number, the institutions of money have created a fantasy world economy grounded in a grand illusion that money is real wealth and that making money creates real wealth to the benefit of all.

Since financial logic favors current returns over future returns and values natural systems only for the financial return they generate, it can lead to dangerously myopic short-term thinking. Here are three examples:
  1. Money in the bank is more valuable than trees in the ground. Some years ago the minister who managed Malaysia’s forests explained to me why Malaysia should clear cut its forests and sell the timber. The interest from the sale would grow faster in the bank than the trees grow in the forest. I imagined a lifeless Malaysian landscape populated only by banks housing computers faithfully calculating the interest payments on Malaysia’s savings deposits.
  2.  Financial bubbles create wealth. A 1996 article in Foreign Affairs, “Securities: The New World Wealth Machine argued that the key to wealth creation is no longer the production of real goods and services, but rather the inflation of financial bubbles based on securitized assets. The argument was so absurd I at first thought the article was a joke. It wasn’t. The article circulated widely on Wall Street and reportedly helped inspire the mortgage securitization frenzy that crashed the economy in 2008.
  3. Your fishery collapsed? No problem. A 1997 article in the culinary section of The New York Times urged readers not to worry about the collapse of Atlantic fisheries, because abundant supplies of delicious fish were being flown in each day from Chile and Thailand and were even cheaper than local varieties because of cheap labor. No mention of a global decline in fish stocks as the number of hungry mouths in the world continues to grow. 
Read more :  http://www.yesmagazine.org/blogs/david-korten/rio-20-a-defining-choice

quinta-feira, 14 de junho de 2012

Media Consolidation : The Illusion of Choice (Infographic)

http://frugaldad.com/2011/11/22/media-consolidation-infographic/
As a dad (and blogger) I’m concerned with the integrity of the news and entertainment my family and I consume every day. Who really produces, owns and airs the shows my kids are glued to every evening and which companies select the stories I read with such loyalty each morning? I’ve always advocated for critical consumption, and what could be more important than an awareness of the sources of our families’ daily info and entertainment diets? And today, most of our media is controlled by one of six companies.

quarta-feira, 13 de junho de 2012

State of the World 2012 : Moving Toward Sustainable Prosperity

http://islandpress.org/ip/books/book/islandpress/S/bo8634584.html

In the 2012 edition of its flagship report, Worldwatch celebrates the twentieth anniversary of the 1992 Earth Summit with a far-reaching analysis of progress toward building sustainable economies. Written in clear language with easy-to-read charts, State of the World 2012 offers a new perspective on what changes and policies will be necessary to make sustainability a permanent feature of the world's economies. The Worldwatch Institute has been named one of the top three environmental think tanks in the world by the University of Pennsylvania's Think Tanks and Civil Societies Program.
http://www.worldwatch.org/stateoftheworld2012

terça-feira, 12 de junho de 2012

Fred Pearce - The Land Grabbers : The New Fight over Who Owns the Earth

http://www.barnesandnoble.com/w/the-land-grabbers-fred-pearce/1110927417

How Wall Street, Chinese billionaires, oil sheiks, and agribusiness are buying up huge tracts of land in a hungry, crowded world.

An unprecedented land grab is taking place around the world. Fearing future food shortages or eager to profit from them, the world’s wealthiest and most acquisitive countries, corporations, and individuals have been buying and leasing vast tracts of land around the world. The scale is astounding: parcels the size of small countries are being gobbled up across the plains of Africa, the paddy fields of Southeast Asia, the jungles of South America, and the prairies of Eastern Europe. Veteran science writer Fred Pearce spent a year circling the globe to find out who was doing the buying, whose land was being taken over, and what the effect of these massive land deals seems to be.

The Land Grabbers is a first-of-its-kind exposé that reveals the scale and the human costs of the land grab, one of the most profound ethical, environmental, and economic issues facing the globalized world in the twenty-first century. The corporations, speculators, and governments scooping up land cheap in the developing world claim that industrial-scale farming will help local economies. But Pearce’s research reveals a far more troubling reality. While some mega-farms are ethically run, all too often poor farmers and cattle herders are evicted from ancestral lands or cut off from water sources. The good jobs promised by foreign capitalists and home governments alike fail to materialize. Hungry nations are being forced to export their food to the wealthy, and corporate potentates run fiefdoms oblivious to the country beyond their fences.

Pearce’s story is populated with larger-than-life characters, from financier George Soros and industry tycoon Richard Branson, to Gulf state sheikhs, Russian oligarchs, British barons, and Burmese generals. We discover why Goldman Sachs is buying up the Chinese poultry industry, what Lord Rothschild and a legendary 1970s asset-stripper are doing in the backwoods of Brazil, and what plans a Saudi oil billionaire has for Ethiopia. Along the way, Pearce introduces us to the people who actually live on, and live off of, the supposedly “empty” land that is being grabbed, from Cambodian peasants, victimized first by the Khmer Rouge and now by crony capitalism, to African pastoralists confined to ever-smaller tracts.

Over the next few decades, land grabbing may matter more, to more of the planet’s people, than even climate change. It will affect who eats and who does not, who gets richer and who gets poorer, and whether agrarian societies can exist outside corporate control. It is the new battle over who owns the planet.

Fred Pearce is a freelance author and journalist based in the UK. He is environment consultant for New Scientist magazine and author of numerous books, including Earth Then and Now: Potent Visual Evidence of Our Changing World, and The Climate Files: The Battle for the Truth About Global Warming.
http://e360.yale.edu/author/Fred_Pearce/19/

What Is a Ponzi Scheme? - Planet Ponzi

http://planetponzi.com/blog/what-is-a-ponzi-scheme

A Ponzi Scheme applies to any investment scheme where the promoter offers crazy returns to attract investors. If you invest your money in such a scheme, you might even get it back – plus some crazy rate of interest – as long as there’s still a flood of money from new investors. But the scheme is still as bankrupt as heck and, once the flood of new money dries up, the entire scheme collapses. And that’s the planet we live on now. Everyone’s borrowing, no one’s paying. And one day, the merry-go-round will stop.

You know that scene in Mr. Smith Goes to Washington? The one where the good guy, Jimmy Stewart, stands up in the Senate protesting the graft and corruption he sees all around him. He’s not as smart as the other Senators. He was only elected by accident and knows that he’s not properly qualified to sit in the legislature of the United States.

But still. He’s Jimmy Stewart. He knows right from wrong and he knows that graft and corruption is wrong, no matter how slick the justification or how nice the suit. He makes a long, wonderful, stirring speech – if you haven’t seen the movie, you ought to – and he keeps coming back to the fundamental point of common sense. At one point, he says, ‘Either I’m dead right, or I’m crazy!’

And he’s not crazy.

This blog is the same. I am, as it happens, a hedge fund manager who’s spent thirty years working in the financial markets. As a result, I know a lot about the world’s financial system and how it works. But you don’t have to be a technical wizard to understand these things. The government of the United States owes 100% of American GDP. That’s insane.

The Federal Reserve is charged with preserving the value of the currency, but it has printed trillions of dollars in new money. When inflation is galloping away. And the Fed doesn’t even know where those trillions have disappeared to. That’s insane.

The Congressional Budget Office tells us that Medicare spending is going to bankrupt the budget. (You can see their chart of federal debt here.) We’re not talking about a few bucks of overspend, but a cost tsunami which will utterly destroy every fiscal rule ever invented. That’s insane.

The Tea Party crowd want us to cut taxes, even though we don’t have enough revenues to cover our expenses as it is. And a tax cut when the nation is in deficit is really a tax increase, because you have to pay the money back again, and with interest. More insanity.

And Wall Street bosses pay themselves extraordinary bonuses even though their stock prices are tanking. That’s not capitalism as I ever understood it. You can call it insanity if you wish, or criminality if you prefer. Either way, I don’t like it.

But these things aren’t confined to the United States. In Britain, we see the same thing: investment banking bosses trashing their company’s share price, bankrupting the government, causing a massive recession – and walking away as multi-millionaires.

In Italy, we see Silvio Berlusconi, the political world’s greatest idiot, presenting an ‘austerity budget’ to Parliament which would make him personally €750 million richer.

The Greek government has been obviously bankrupt for years, but it’s taken till now for Europe to recognize the fact.

The European Union announces a ‘rescue plan’ that will impose vast costs on the ‘strong’ governments, but which has obviously failed within a couple of days of the announcement.

It’s all insane. And not just insane – it’s wrong. Ethically, financially, and socially wrong. Much of it is also, in my opinion, illegal and should be punished by long terms in jail.

This blog is about these issues. It’ll shout out when politicians and bankers do things wrong. It’ll cheer on those rare occasions when politicians get things right. We’ll also talk about the dollar in your purse, the pound in your pocket. The value of your savings is under threat and, as a professional investment manager, I’ll share with you my philosophy on how to preserve your savings from destruction. These are dangerous times and they’re only just starting.

Source : http://planetponzi.com/blog/what-is-a-ponzi-scheme
"Os povos serão cultos na medida em que entre eles crescer o número dos que se negam a aceitar qualquer benefício dos que podem; dos que se mantêm sempre vigilantes em defesa dos oprimidos não porque tenham este ou aquele credo político, mas por isso mesmo, porque são oprimidos e neles se quebram as leis da Humanidade e da razão; dos que se levantam, sinceros e corajosos, ante as ordens injustas, não também porque saem de um dos campos em luta, mas por serem injustas; dos que acima de tudo defendem o direito de pensar e de ser digno"
- Agostinho da Silva, “O Terceiro Caminho”, Diário de Alcestes [1945], in Textos e Ensaios Filosóficos I, p. 217. 

Fonte : http://arevistaentre.blogspot.pt/2010/12/os-povos-serao-cultos-na-medida-em-que.html

Alejandro Nadal (La Jornada) Economia verde, novo disfarce do neoliberalismo

http://envolverde.com.br/economia/economia-verde-economia/economia-verde-novo-disfarce-do-neoliberalismo/

Em meio à mais grave crise da economia capitalista em escala mundial, a deterioração ambiental foi relegada a um segundo plano. É verdade que se diz alguma coisa sobre a perda da biodiversidade ou a mudança climática. Mas, de fato, o meio ambiente não é prioridade.

Os termos do debate sobre a crise foram impostos pela direita e em sua tela do radar o problema ambiental sempre ocupou um lugar subsidiário. Por isto, não surpreende que, agora que os centros de poder castigam com austeridade fiscal e promovem a destruição de qualquer vestígio do estado de bem-estar, o meio ambiente brilhe por sua ausência. E quando se pretende tratá-lo como tema prioritário, a realidade é que é apenas para manter o projeto neoliberal em escala global.

O Programa das Nações Unidas para o Meio Ambiente (Pnuma) promove nos últimos três anos uma série de projetos que se enquadram no que vem chamando de Iniciativa de Economia Verde (IEV). Este projeto define uma economia verde como o resultado de melhorias no bem-estar humano e na equidade social, ao mesmo tempo que se reduzem os riscos ambientais e a escassez ecológica. O Pnuma sustenta que o manejo eficiente dos recursos ambientais oferece oportunidades econômicas importantes. Finalmente, afirma que uma economia verde deve ser baixa no uso de combustíveis fósseis e socialmente includente. Esta retórica pode dar uma boa impressão. Mas a realidade é que a iniciativa do Pnuma sofre de grandes defeitos que, ao final das contas, anulam o que poderia aparecer como bons desejos. O que fica é um disfarce mal armado para dar uma cara amável ao neoliberalismo do ponto de vista ambiental.

O primeiro grande problema da IEV é a incapacidade de examinar as causas da destruição ambiental. Nenhuma das forças econômicas que provocam a deterioração ambiental é objeto de uma análise cuidadosa. Nem a concentração do poder econômico em centros corporativos, nem os processos de acumulação de terras em grandes regiões da África e América Latina, nem o efeito da especulação financeira sobre produtos básicos, nem o peso enorme da dívida dos países mais pobres do mundo são temas importantes para o Pnuma. Em contraste, abunda a retórica sobre instrumentos de política baseados no mecanismo de mercado e a necessidade de estimular os investimentos privados.

O Pnuma também ignora as causas da feroz desigualdade, que é o traço dominante na economia mundial. Parece que esta caiu do céu, como se se tratasse de um fenômeno meteorológico. Assim, a IEV fala da necessidade de aliviar e, inclusive, de eliminar a pobreza. Mas sempre que faz, o faz em referência ao potencial que oferece o bom manejo dos recursos. Nunca se menciona a necessidade de corrigir a marcada tendência contra os salários reais. Sabe-se de sobra que, em quase todo o mundo, os salários reais experimentam um declínio importante a partir dos anos 1970. Entre as causas mais visíveis desse resultado está a repressão salarial imposta para controlar a demanda agregada e, desse modo, levar adiante a luta contra a inflação (o principal inimigo do capital financeiro). Apesar da importância desta variável da distribuição, a palavra salários não consta no dicionário da IEV.

A desigualdade também está fortemente ancorada em uma política fiscal regressiva. Contudo, quando se trata de recomendações em matéria de política fiscal, o documento do Pnuma sugere que o melhor marco fiscal para o crescimento deve descansar nos impostos indiretos e nas baixas taxas tributárias para o setor corporativo. Isto deve ir acompanhado de maior eficiência no gasto público, o que no jargão neoliberal se traduz em maiores ajustes e geração de um superávit primário para pagar encargos financeiros. Claro, as referências do Pnuma são a OCDE, o Banco Mundial e a consultoria PriceWaterhouseCoopers. Isto sim, alerta sobre os riscos de impor cargas ao capital financeiro.

Embora a iniciativa do Pnuma se baseie na ideia de que a crise oferece a oportunidade para reencaminhar a economia mundial pelo caminho do desenvolvimento sustentável, nenhum documento do organismo contém uma análise séria sobre as origens e a natureza da crise. Os leitores podem corroborar o que foi dito anteriormente na página da IEV (www.unep.org/greeneconomy). Por extraordinário que pareça, uma análise séria sobre a crise e suas ramificações não é relevante para falar da transição para uma economia verde.

A iniciativa do Pnuma procura alongar a vida do modelo neoliberal. É também um bom exemplo da sentença de Keynes: não apenas fracassamos na tentativa de compreender a ordem econômica na qual vivemos, como também a interpretamos mal a ponto de adotar medidas que operam duramente contra nós.

* A ECO 21 agradece a gentileza de IHU-Unisinos. Tradução: Cepat.

** Publicado originalmente no site Eco21.

Ray Bush and Habib Ayeb : Marginality And Exclusion In Egypt And The Middle East

http://www.zedbooks.co.uk/paperback/marginality-and-exclusion-in-egypt

What does it mean to be marginalized? Is it a passive condition that the disadvantaged simply have to endure? Or is it a manufactured label, reproduced and by its nature transitory?

In the wake of the new uprising in Egypt, this insightful collection explores issues of power, politics and inequality in Egypt and the Middle East. It argues that the notion of marginality tends to mask the true power relations that perpetuate poverty and exclusion. It is these dynamic processes of political and economic transformation that need explanation.

The book provides a revealing analysis of key areas of Egyptian political economy, such as labour, urbanization and the creation of slums, disability, refugees, street children, and agrarian livelihoods, reaching the impactful conclusion that marginalization does not mean total exclusion. What is marginalized can be called upon to play a dynamic part in the future -- as is the case with the revolution that toppled President Mubarak.

Table of Contents

Part One: Marginality, poverty and political economy
1 Introduction: Marginality and exclusion in Egypt and the Middle East
Ray Bush and Habib Ayeb
2 Marginality: curse or cure?
Asef Bayat
3 Accumulation by encroachment in the Arab Mashreq
Ali Kadri

Part Two: Creating and reproducing marginality
4 Marginality or abjection? The political economy of poverty production in Egypt
Ray Bush
5 The marginalization of the small peasantry: Egypt and Tunisia
Habib Ayeb
6 Margins and frontiers
Reem Saad
7 Transport thugs: spatial marginalization in a Cairo suburb
Dalia Wahdan
8 Against marginalization: workers, youth and class in the 25 January revolution
Rabab el Mahdi
9 National geographical targeting of poverty in Upper Egypt
Saker el Nour
10 Working with street kids: unsettling accounts from the field
Kamal Fahmi
11 Marginalization and self-marginalization: commercial education and its graduates
Moushira Elgeziri
12 Disability in transition in Egypt: between marginalization and rights
Heba Hagrass

About the Authors:

Ray Bush is Professor of African Studies and Development Politics at the University of Leeds, UK. He is deputy chair of the Review of African Political Economy. His most recent book is Poverty and Neoliberalism: Persistence and Reproduction in the Global South (2007). His work focuses on the political economy of economic reform, resources, social and rural transformation.

Habib Ayeb is a researcher at the Social Research Center at the American University in Cairo. His research focuses on agrarian change, water resources, poverty and marginality. He has worked in the Ministry of Agriculture in Tunisia, the University of Paris 8-St Denis, CEDEJ (Centre d’Etudes et de Documentation Juridiques et Sociales), IRD (Institute of Research for Development) and the SRC.

Manfred Max-Neef - From the Outside Looking in : Experiences in Barefoot Economics

http://zed-books.blogspot.pt/2011/03/barefoot-economics.html

Barefoot Economics - It's time for economists to start getting dirty. From an interview with Manfred Max-Neef on Democracy Now!. Manfred Max-Neef is an acclaimed Chilean economist and a recipient of the Right Livelihood Award. He is the author of "From the Outside Looking in: Experiences in Barefoot Economics" (published by Zed Books in 1992) and the upcoming "Economics Unmasked: From Power and Greed to Compassion and the Common Good." - This article was taken from Adbusters.

From the Outside Looking in: Experiences in ‘Barefoot Economics’, by Manfred A Max-Neef. Uppsala, 1982, 208 pp. This book contains two Latin American case studies, ‘Horizontal Communication for Peasants’ Participation and Self-reliance’ and ‘Revitalization of Small Cities for Self-reliance’. (Out of stock) Reprinted 1992 by Zed Books Ltd, 57 Caledonian Road, London N1 9BU, UK, (ISBN 1 85649 187 0 Hb, 1 85649 188 9 Pb).
Available in pdf format

I worked for about ten years in areas of extreme poverty in the Sierras, in the jungle and urban areas of Latin America. And one day at the beginning of that period I found myself in an Indian village in the Sierra in Peru. It was an ugly day. It had been raining all day. And I was standing in the slum. And across from me, a guy was standing in the mud – not in the slum, in the mud. He was a short guy … thin, hungry, jobless, five kids, a wife and a grandmother. And I was the fine economist from Berkeley. As we looked at each other, I suddenly realized that I had nothing coherent to say to that man in those circumstances, that my whole language as an economist was absolutely useless. Should I tell him that he should be happy because the GDP had grown five percent or something? Everything felt absurd. Economists study and analyze poverty in their nice offices, they have all the statistics, they make all the models and are convinced they know everything. But they don’t understand poverty.

I live in the south of Chile in the deep south. And that area is known for its milk production. Top technologically, and in every way the best there is. A few months ago I was in a hotel there for breakfast, and there were these little butter things. I looked at one. It was butter from New Zealand. And I thought, isn’t that crazy? Why? The answer is because economists don’t know how to calculate true costs. To bring butter from 10,000 kilometers to a place where you already make the best butter, under the argument that it is cheaper, is a colossal stupidity. They don’t take into consideration the environmental impact of 10,000 kilometers of transport. And part of the reason it’s cheaper is because it’s subsidized. So it’s clearly a case in which the prices do not tell the truth. It’s all tricks. And those tricks do colossal harm. If you bring consumption closer to production, you will eat better, you will have better food, you will know where it comes from and you may even know the person who produces it. You will humanize consumption. But the way economics is practiced today is totally dehumanized.

We need cultured economists, economists who know the history, where the ideas come from, how the ideas originated, who did what; an economics that understands itself very clearly as a subsystem of the larger system of the biosphere. Today’s economists know nothing about ecosystems, nothing about thermodynamics, nothing about biodiversity – they are totally ignorant in those respects. And I don’t see what harm it would do to an economist to know that if the beasts and nature disappear, he would disappear as well because there wouldn’t be food to eat. But today’s economists don’t know that we depend absolutely on nature. For them, nature is a subsystem of our economy. It’s absolutely crazy!

segunda-feira, 11 de junho de 2012

New Paradigm in Macroeconomics : Solving the Riddle of Japanese Macroeconomic

http://www.palgrave.com/products/title.aspx?PID=268353

Modern mainstream economics is attracting an increasing number of critics of its high degree of abstraction and lack of relevance to economic reality. Economists are calling for a better reflection of the reality of imperfect information, the role of banks and credit markets, the mechanisms of economic growth, the role of institutions and the possibility that markets may not clear. While it is one thing to find flaws in current mainstream economics, it is another to offer an alternative paradigm which can explain as much as the old, but can also account for the many 'anomalies'. That is what this book attempts. Since one of the biggest empirical challenges to the 'old' paradigm has been raised by the second largest economy in the world - Japan - this book puts the proposed 'new paradigm' to the severe test of the Japanese macroeconomic reality. In the process, the many 'puzzles' surrounding Japan's economy are explained. However, the new paradigm is found applicable far beyond Japan and provides a consistent explanation of events in many industrialised economies and emerging markets. It also overturns the 'Washington consensus' package of economic development policies and presents a starkly different vision of modern economic policy and its potential to improve our lives.

Richard Werner has been at the University of Southampton since 2004. He is Director of International Development and founding Director of the Centre for Banking, Finance and Sustainable Development. Richard is also a member of the Southampton Management School's Executive Board, as well as its Advisory Board. 
http://www.southampton.ac.uk/management/about/staff/werner.page

A Conversation with Herman Daly

We are grateful to Herman Daly for chatting with us on a range of topics from ecology to economics, policy to politics, relocalization to religion. He is Emeritus Professor at the University of Maryland School of Public Policy, pioneered work on Steady-State and Ecological Economics, and has received more accolades and written more books than we can mention. Find more about Steady-State Economics at steadystate.org, and reach out to your elected officials about the need to transition to a steady-state economy.

You have been making a persuasive case for a steady-state economy (SSE) for several decades now. In that time, we’ve gone well into ecological overshoot. The Limits to Growth scenarios indicate it may no longer be possible to avoid decline/collapse as delayed negative effects begin to kick in. What gives you hope that a transition to a steady-state economy is still possible?

The steady state to which we might now transition will be a smaller and more impoverished one than our existing level, or one that we could have attained if we had started sooner. A small amount of optimism comes from the fact that growth has become uneconomic and our self-interest may help us recognize that, once we properly measure costs and benefits. But beyond such limited rational optimism is faith-based hope. If one believes the world is in some sense a creation rather than a random accident, and that purpose can be independently causative in the physical world, albeit within limits, then there is a basis for hope. If one believes that purpose (final causation) is an illusion, a trick evolution played on us, as many materialists affirm, then we might as well forget it all anyway and try to “have fun” while it lasts.

In control systems, two properties that are important, among others, are convergence and stability—that is, how well, if at all, does the system move towards the desired operating point, and how well does it stay there once it arrives at that point.

Regarding convergence, do you think there’s a way to arrest the harmful, delayed feedbacks that are already underway using the levers of SSE? It seems one of the fundamental issues in an economic or industrial system is the feedback delay between changes in the system and their effects; it’s this dynamic that Meadows et al. observed as causing overshoot and decline/collapse. How might you avoid this in a steady-state system, especially when the delayed feedback can be in the form of a problem that develops for years before scientists even become aware of it (e.g. the ozone hole), let alone form a consensus (e.g. climate change)?

I don’t think of a SSE as automatically converging to a stable operating point, but more as a system whose inherent tendency is to outgrow its parent system, and which must therefore be externally constrained. Thus the equilibrium will be at a limit, and the important thing is to set that limit within the larger carrying capacity and carefully enforce it. (This is an important difference with neoclassical environmental economists who think they can make the economy internally convergent and stable by just “getting prices right” and putting a price on everything). The uncertainty about where the limits are, and the delayed feedback from exceeding them are very real problems, and the only “answer” I have is to slow down and leave a bigger margin for ignorance—the so-called precautionary principle—as I am told the engineers do—design a bridge you think will last, and then double its strength for good measure.

Might there be an analogous stability problem to The Energy Trap that arises out of political myopia, in which there is an incentive to rig the system once it has arrived at the steady-state target to squeeze a little bit of short-term gain out of it? What might be done to keep politicians (and those that support and elect them) from changing the rules of the game in this way for temporary benefit? (Might there be broader, more permanent rules, akin to Alaska’s constitutional mandate on sustainable fishing, that would prevent such action?)

The more one specifies permanent rules the less able one is to make adjustments to meet changing conditions. Any system can be subverted by the people running it—witness the repeal of the Glass-Steagall Act. The quest for a “system so perfect that no one needs to be good” (T.S. Eliot) is likely to fail.

Suppose you could make every layperson familiar with one economic concept. What would it be, and why? Given the kind of reportage we get on matters economic, what should people be paying attention to, and what should just be ignored?

I suppose it would be “opportunity cost”, the worth of the next best alternative to the one chosen, the best set of opportunities sacrificed in making a choice. Don’t worry about monetizing it at first, just make a list (without double counting) of the most important things you can’t do because of what you chose to do, and calmly think about whether your chosen alternative would really be worth it. Then try to monetize the cost. We should ignore incessant reportage on the Dow-Jones, and GDP growth, and demand better reporting and measurement of unemployment, income distribution, and rates of depletion and pollution.

How can the concept of opportunity cost help laypersons? Does it help them make choices in daily life? If so, what might be an example? Or is it better for evaluating candidate policies?

Suppose I want to become a great singer, but have limited talent. Maybe I just need to devote all my time and energy to singing and practicing. But what else could I be doing with my time and energy—what opportunities am I sacrificing in my quest to become a great singer? Is it worth it?—A very commonsense idea.

You have argued that GDP conflates utility and throughput; might there be some simple definition or definitions of utility that could be computed using statistics collected by governments today? (Are the Human Development Index, Genuine Progress Indicator, and others like them good proxies for utility?)

GPI is an objective index of utility, and self-evaluated happiness is a subjective index—both show a positive correlation with GDP up to a point beyond which GDP continues to rise and the utility index becomes flat. So although there is no direct measure of utility, there is good evidence that, beyond a sufficiency, GDP growth does not increase it.

How would you sell SSE to someone whose understanding of economics comes from the nightly news—one dominated by growth, the stock market, and unemployment data? How would you sell steady-state economic policy to progressives / liberals vs. conservatives?

I would point out that all the growth has gone to the rich, and that the poor have actually lost ground in the last few decades, so the claim that growth will cure poverty has proven false. As for the stock market—the Dow-Jones is mostly meaningless day-to-day noise, but the recent crash brought on by over leverage and fraudulent financial manipulation should make one very wary of the stock market—and indeed of our fractional reserve banking system. It should convince us of the need to move toward 100% reserve requirements and to break-up large banks. Unemployment statistics are an important feedback that reflects large loss of welfare, and the figures are usually underestimated. It used to be that full employment was the goal and growth in GDP the means to it. Now growth is the goal, and off-shoring jobs, merger, and automation, which increase unemployment, are the means. Since liberals are as afraid of a steady state as conservatives, I would make the same points to them.

The highest-profile source—or vehicle, really—of information about the massive gains for the rich since 1970 is Occupy Wall Street. And thinking about OWS brings many questions to mind. Although there was some misleading coverage of OWS, especially at first, for a few weeks the mainstream media were showing people with economic grievances, and taking them seriously. And OWS also took issue explicitly with the engineers of the 2008 financial crisis.

Nonetheless, Occupy Wall Street has been effectively disappeared from media coverage, the camps displaced, and the issues dismissed by ad hominem—e.g. it’s only lazy hippies who complain. Is this a sign that the information people need is inherently unwelcome? Was OWS the wrong spokesmovement for economic justice?

No, I think they had as much impact as possible, given that Wall Street owns the media.

Do you still believe that “it will probably take a Great Ecological Spasm to convince people that something is wrong with an economic theory that denies the very possibility of an economy exceeding its optimal scale” (as you wrote in 1987)? (Or for a real paradigm shift to happen will it require, to put Kuhn’s observation nicely, that today’s conventional economists retire?) Have we foreclosed some outcomes having waited over twenty years from that writing?

Yes. The financial crisis of 2008 and continuing recession have not been enough—indeed they have placed growth even more front and center because it is the only “solution” economists and politicians can imagine. I used to expect a Kuhnian paradigm shift as old economists died off, but they seem to be cloning themselves in university economics departments faster than they are dying. As noted above we have certainly foreclosed some options by delay, and the Millennial generation of economists do not seem to be an improvement, with the exception of ecological economists who are still very rare in academic economics departments. I hope the new generation will not be bluffed by their economists, but will insist on better answers to critical questions.

In For the Common Good, you made a compelling case for the revitalization of communities, and for bottom-up rethinking of social arrangements. It seems however that there are structural economic and political barriers that communities face if they try to relocalize: everything from outsourced manufacturing to the Commerce Clause. What might be some ways around this? Might it require informal / gray-market local economies or policies (and might local currencies, timebanks, and other similar mechanisms play a role)?

Of course one way is global crash followed by reconstruction at more local and national levels. Increasing energy and transportation costs could bring about re-localization more gradually. Off-shoring production and global economic integration is a sell-out of the working class in the interest of transnational corporations, and at some point has to be politically resisted. The disintegration of the Eurozone may be the first step in re-localization. Local currencies as a supplement to national currencies are a good idea especially for depressed areas that have to export to the national economy just to earn cash with which to transact even local exchanges. The fallacies of free trade and globalization are discussed in For the Common Good, chapter 11. I think the first step in re-localization is to de-globalize or re-nationalize. Relatively independent nations can trade for mutual benefit, but extreme specialization means you must trade. If trade is no longer voluntary there is no reason to expect it to be mutually beneficial.

Have we in the United States (and, to a lesser extent, Europe and the rest of the industrialized world) reached a point of diminishing returns not just in terms of EROEI but in something related: the return we get from tapping the resources of nations around the globe via economic (and military) means? Is there a means by which we in the United States can extricate ourselves from our involvement in and wealth-siphoning from countless nations around the globe in a way that isn’t severely damaging both for us and the nations in question?

Already wars are caused by competition for remaining oil, and increasingly for agricultural land and water. Growth economies will be driven to resource wars, and avoiding that is a major reason for steady state economies. R & D should go into improving resource productivity, not into military weapons for gaining access to remaining resources. Move away from globalization (integrated world economy dominated by transnational corporations) toward trade among interdependent but relatively self-sufficient national economies, as was envisioned at Bretton Woods, and then abandoned with the later formation of the WTO and its promotion of free capital mobility and global economic integration.

We’ve been wondering for a while how to be sneaky and achieve the end goals of a steady-state economy through different means. That is, suppose we come to terms with the fact that the economic and political systems are what they are, and are going to resist open change to a SSE. What stealth approaches might political leaders or activists use to make the needed changes piecemeal but without letting on about the overall end goal? Might there be a way to achieve the goals of steady-state economics during a transition period without letting on that we’ve abandoned growth? That is, might there be some policy (likely monetary, though perhaps fiscal and otherwise) that could create the appearance of growth given the statistics and metrics we use today while at the same time in fact behaving like an SSE? Similarly, are there systems today (either in the private or public sector) that could be co-opted to function as SSE mechanisms?

I think there are policies that foster a steady state indirectly, and have other reasons in their favor that might be emphasized (100% reserve requirements for banking system). But their negative consequences for growth are soon realized and are raised as an argument against them. I have argued for a set of ten policies, each of which would contribute towards a steady state, and all of which together might be sufficient. Although the ten policies supplement and balance each other to some degree, most could be enacted piecemeal for reasons short of attaining a steady state economy.

Might it be the case that implementing any specific preferred system for society would be counterproductive or less effective than we’d like if it didn’t evolve organically? (That is, if rulemaking itself wasn’t relocalized.) Is there some minimal framework of concepts from SSE that could be extracted (meta-rules)—that is, the paradigm, not the system—within which local and national societies could establish their own rules to operate at a steady state, and if so what might that be?

Meta-rules for SSE: limit population; limit throughput; limit the range of income inequality permitted. Within those limits let markets allocate resources, with exception made for non rival goods.

While we strongly believe in the need to let science guide the ways in which an SSE is boxed in and kept within ecological limits, might there be a blindspot in this approach? Specifically, might it fall into a sort of neutral technocrat fallacy, in which the biases of those who manage this crucial aspect of the system go unexamined? (Consider for example the natural resource extraction limits that are set, or the maximum and minimum wages incomes that are set.) Are there ways of instituting real checks and balances here? Would the constitution need to be amended to enshrine the principles of steady-state economics, and if so, how?

There is always a danger of the “neutral technocrat” fallacy as we have certainly experienced in connection with the overwhelming technocratic support of the growth economy. My major worry about “scientific blindness”, as I have experienced it in ecological economics, comes from the biologist/ecologist commitment to neodarwinist fundamentalism. By that I do not mean descent from a common ancestor, for which there is abundant evidence, but rather the metaphysics of materialism and random randomness as sufficient causes for explaining everything. This view is often connected with neodarwinist evolutionary theory, as a key part of their animus against any idea of creation or a creator or purpose in any meaningful sense. This scientific materialist methodology is understandable as a working hypothesis, but when elevated to a metaphysical worldview, quickly and logically leads to nihilism.

This undercuts policy of any kind, including environmental policy. I hasten to add that biologists and ecologists have been at the forefront of environmental protection, but there is a deep lurking inconsistency between their actions and their professed philosophy that does not support their actions. In a way this is the opposite inconsistency from the Christians whose belief in Creation gives them every reason to responsibly care for it, yet have in practice failed to do so. Neodarwinist ecologists have no reason to care for creation yet in practice do so, perhaps unconsciously drawing on the early history of their discipline in natural theology. Over time I fear this practical commitment will wither from lack of religious foundation.

It’s true that theists have a reason to care about the natural world that atheists lack. But don’t theists and atheists alike have many other reasons to preserve the environment and enact good policy? For example, anyone could act out of concern for other humans, future generations, the beauty of nature, the welfare of nonhuman creatures, or even simple self-interest. If a scientist or politician genuinely cares to preserve ecological systems, does it really matter whether they’re acting out of religious concern rather than for one of these other reasons?

Isn’t it quite common, in general, to hold contradictory beliefs but act consistently on one of them? Everyone has some inconsistencies in their belief set, but this doesn’t usually prevent people from acting. I might consistently act on the belief that P even though I hold beliefs inconsistent with P, especially if I’m not aware of that inconsistency. So, supposing that a materialist metaphysics really does entail nihilism (for the record, I don’t believe it does), why should we expect scientist policymakers to act like nihilists, rather than simply continue to act as though there are genuine values?

If one refuses to act on a set of beliefs that contradict another set of beliefs that one does act on, then I would say that one doesn’t really believe the first (inoperative) set of “beliefs”. The world is full of people who profess materialist determinism, yet they make decisions and blame themselves and others for mistakes and immoral choices. If one is unaware of the inconsistency then we have an obligation to raise his awareness. Perhaps it is not atheism per se that entails nihilism, but rather the beliefs, the worldview, that lead many to atheism in the modern world, namely materialist determinism plus randomness over immense time periods. Most atheists of this usual type grew up in a culture saturated with the Judeo-Christian tradition (in the West, or another religion elsewhere) and absorbed the associated moral values with their mothers milk. They will not ” simply continue to act as though there are genuine values” as the basis for belief in genuine values atrophies in light of their ”knowledge” that values are mere survival mechanisms governed by materialist forces guided by randomness. Continued appeal to the beauty of nature, future generations, etc. becomes free-floating sentimentality with no objective foundation.

What do you think of James Hansen’s conclusion that climate scientists (and in general those working to raise awareness on overshoot), given that decades of warnings have had no impact, need to take direct action (as Hansen has, going to jail for protesting against coal)?

I agree with his serious concern about climate change, and very much admire him for his courage and willingness to engage in peaceful civil disobedience. I do not, however, understand his antipathy to cap-auction-trade as a policy for limiting greenhouse gasses. I think he overstates the differences with tax policy, and underestimates the advantage of fixing quantity from the beginning and thereby ruling out the Jevons or rebound effect of efficiency increase.

One of the strongest cultural forces in the U.S. is Christianity, and the Biblical heritage has sometimes been blamed (notably by Lynn White) for exploitation of the nonhuman world. Whether or not that historical thesis is true, U.S. Christianity currently seems to be aligned with the drill-baby-drill crowd, and the occasional politician will even claim that God won’t let us run out of resources. But there is also a Christian environmentalism on the move, which sees passages like Genesis 1:26–28 as a demand for stewardship of the planet and its life. Do you think there is a way to make stewardship part of mainstream Christianity? Would doing so change the kind of environmental politics we see in the U.S.?

To my fellow Christians, and others, I recommend Richard Baukham’s book, Bible and Ecology (Rediscovering the Community of Creation) as a much-needed correction to the “drill-baby-drill” exercise of dominion. Christians have a lot to repent of regarding care of creation, and many, in addition to Bauckham, are certainly doing so. But at the same time Christians have a theology of creation that supports environmental policy much better than does a metaphysics of purposeless random materialism. Without strong support from a reawakened Christian faith I doubt that environmental destruction and economic collapse can be avoided, at least in the US. Will other faiths in other cultures be able to arrest the collapse? I don’t know. The dominant belief that modern science and technology (which also have a lot to repent of but unfortunately lack the concept) are sufficient, is in my view a replay of the Gnostic heresy.

Have you or others tried to understand prior sustainable societies of the world in the context of your economic theories? Are there practices that you thought were necessary for sustainability that were absent, or vice-versa?

I am afraid that I have not really dealt with this important question, although others have.

What do you think those of us in the Millennial Generation understand better or worse than those of generations past about these challenges? What generational strengths should we leverage and weaknesses should we avoid?

As I mentioned earlier I have been disappointed that there has not been a Kuhnian revolution in economics in which the new paradigm (ecological economics, steady-state economics) replaces the old, because the old growth economists have been cloning themselves in university economics departments faster than they are dying. So I hope that in the new generation other scholars will invade the discipline of economics and do the job that my generation of economists has failed to do. Ecological economists are trying, but still are very much marginalized. Some physicists have made an important contribution here; others have just become rich Wall Street “quants”. Again I am hopeful, but not very optimistic.

Thank you for taking the time to chat with us. Is there anything important we’ve missed or anything else you’d like to share with us?

Was a pleasure to have such a stimulating discussion with you. I hope you continue your invasion of the discipline of economics!

Source : http://contraposition.org/blog/2012/02/24/a-conversation-with-herman-daly/